Perhaps because of Monopoly, certainly
because of WorldCom, and for many other reasons, the focus of this book has been
the stock market, not the bond market (or real estate, commodities, and other
worthy investments). Stocks are, of course, shares of ownership in a company,
whereas bonds are loans to a company or government, and “everybody knows” that
bonds are generally safer and less volatile than stocks, although the latter
have a higher rate of return. In fact, as Jeremy Siegel reports in Stocks for the Long Run, the average annual rate of return
for stocks between 1802 and 1997 was 8.4 percent; the rate on treasury bills
over the same period was between 4 percent and 5 percent. (The rates that follow
are before inflation. What’s needless to say, I hope, is that an 8 percent rate
of return in a year of 15 percent inflation is much worse than a 4 percent
return in a year of 3 percent inflation.)
Despite what “everybody knows,” Siegel
argues in his book that, as with Monopoly’s hotels and railroads, stocks are
actually less risky than bonds because, over the long run, they have performed
so much better than bonds or treasury bills. In fact, the longer the run, the
more likely this has been the case. (Comments like “everybody knows” or “they’re
all doing this” or “everyone’s buying that” usually make me itch. My background
in mathematical logic has made it difficult for me to interpret “all” as
signifying something other than all.) “Everybody” does have a point, however.
How can we believe Siegel’s claims, given that the standard deviation for
stocks’ annual rate of return has been 17.5 percent?
If we assume a normal distribution and
allow ourselves to get numerical for a couple of paragraphs, we can see how
stomach-churning this volatility is. It means that about two-thirds of the time,
the rate of return will be between -9.1 percent and 25.9 percent (that is, 8.4
percent plus or minus 17.5 percent), and about 95 percent of the time the rate
will be between -26.6 percent and 43.4 percent (that is, 8.4 percent plus or
minus two times 17.5 percent). Although the precision of these figures is
absurd, one consequence of the last assertion is that the returns will be worse
than -26.6 percent about 2.5 percent of the time (and better than 43.4 percent
with the same frequency). So about once every forty years (1/40 is 2.5 percent),
you will lose more than a quarter of the value of your stock investments and
much more frequently than that do considerably worse than treasury
bills.
These numbers certainly don’t seem to
indicate that stocks are less risky than bonds over the long term. The
statistical warrant for Siegel’s contention, however, is that over time, the
returns even out and the deviations shrink. Specifically, the annualized
standard deviation for rates of return over a number N of years is the standard
deviation divided by the square root of N. The larger N is, the smaller is the
standard deviation. (The cumulative standard deviation is, however, greater.)
Thus over any given four-year period the annualized standard deviation for stock
returns is 17.5%/2, or 8.75%. Likewise, since the square root of 30 is about
5.5, the annualized standard deviation of stock returns over any given
thirty-year period is only 17.5%/5.5, or 3.2%. (Note that this annualized
thirty-year standard deviation is the same as the annual standard deviation for
the conservative stock mentioned in the example at the end of chapter
6.)
Despite the impressive historical
evidence, there is no guarantee that stocks will continue to outperform bonds.
If you look at the period from 1982 to 1997, the average annual rate of return
for stocks was 16.7 percent with a standard deviation of 13.1 percent, while the
returns for bonds were between 8 percent and 9 percent. But from 1966 to 1981,
the average annual rate of return for stocks was 6.6 percent with a standard
deviation of 19.5 percent, while the returns for bonds were about 7
percent.
So is it really the case that, despite
the debacles, deadbeats, and doomsday equities like WCOM and Enron, the less
risky long-term investment is in stocks? Not surprisingly, there is a
counterargument. Despite their volatility, stocks as a whole have proven less
risky than bonds over the long run because their average rates of return have
been considerably higher. Their rates of return have been higher because their
prices have been relatively low. And their prices have been relatively low
because they’ve been viewed as risky and people need some inducement to make
risky investments.
But what happens if investors believe
Siegel and others, and no longer view stocks as risky? Then their prices will
rise because risk-averse investors will need less inducement to buy them; the
“equity-risk premium,” the amount by which stock returns must exceed bond
returns to attract investors, will decline. And the rates of return will fall
because prices will be higher. And stocks will therefore be riskier because of
their lower returns.
Viewed as less risky, stocks become
risky; viewed as risky, they become less risky. This is yet another instance of
the skittish, self-reflective, self-corrective dynamic of the market.
Interestingly, Robert Shiller, a personal friend of Siegel, looks at the data
and sees considerably lower stock returns for the next ten years.
Market practitioners as well as
academics disagree. In early October 2002, I attended a debate between Larry
Kudlow, a CNBC commentator and Wall Street fixture, and Bob Prechter, a
technical analyst and Elliot wave proponent. The audience at the CUNY graduate
center in New York seemed affluent and well-educated, and the speakers both
seemed very sure of themselves and their predictions. Neither seemed at all
affected by the other’s diametrically opposed expectations. Prechter anticipated
very steep declines in the market, while Kudlow was quite bullish. Unlike Siegel
and Shiller, they didn’t engage on any particulars and generally talked past
each other.
What I find odd about such encounters
is how typical they are of market discussions. People with impressive
credentials regularly expatiate upon stocks and bonds and come to conclusions
contrary to those of other people with equally impressive credentials. An
article in the New York Times in November 2002 is
another case in point. It described three plausible prognoses for the
market—bad, so-so, and good—put forth by economic analysts Steven H. East,
Charles Pradilla, and Abby Joseph Cohen, respectively. Such stark disagreement
happens very rarely in physics or mathematics. (I’m not counting crackpots who
sometimes receive a lot of publicity but aren’t taken seriously by anybody
knowledgeable.)
The market’s future course may lie
beyond what, in chapter 9, I term the “complexity horizon.” Nevertheless, aside
from some real estate, I remain fully vested in stocks, which may or may not
result in my remaining fully shirted.
ไม่มีความคิดเห็น:
แสดงความคิดเห็น